Attachment 16uAttachment #16-u
P31011
for
2015 ISSUE BRIEFS FOR STATES
Brief Explanations of
Common Alcohol Regulatory Issues
Facing State and Local Communities
Produced by Pamela S. Erickson, President/CEO
Public Action Management, PLC
healffivalcoholmarket.com
January 2015
OO Pamela S. Erickson 2015
An Introduction to the
2015 Issue Briefs for State Policy -Makers
This is a package of simple briefs that address common issues about alcohol regulation. It is designed
for community leaders, elected officials and other policy -makers who need a short, straightforward
explanation of a given issue.
For each brief, research citations are given where they exist. The Appendix lists resources for further
information about a given issue as well as the sources for quotations and facts cited. This publication is issued
annually in order to incorporate current information.
Alcohol problems are complex and impacted by a variety of factors. Drinking is more prevalent in
northern countries and in northern US states. Religious prohibitions may lower consumption rates. Young
people, males and some ethnic groups drink at higher rates. A complex social problem generally requires a
comprehensive system of regulation to address all its facets.
A growing body of research points to the need for a comprehensive system with multiple methods to
contain price, availability, potentially dangerous products and aggressive promotions. These regulations work
together, so changing a single regulation can change the workings of the entire system.
The primary purpose of the alcohol regulatory system and its individual regulations is to protect public
health and safety. Whenever a change is proposed, the first question should be: How will this change affect
public health and safety?
How to use these briefs:
Each brief is designed to stand alone. Please feel free to copy any of them including the attribution to
healthyalcoholmarket.com. If you wish to modify one or more of the briefs, please contact the author, Pamela
S. Erickson, and she will attempt to accommodate your needs. She can be reached at Ramg amaction.com.
Further information can be found at healthyalcoholmarket. com.
New is this edition:
Most of the briefs have received minor editing for updated information and additional clarity. Brief #6
regarding why some states own and operate the liquor business was extensively revised to provide updated
information on Washington State's privatization of liquor and deregulation of wine. #7 has a new map,
courtesy of the National Alcohol Beverage Control Association, which portrays where you can buy beer, wine
and spirits in each state. #16 was substantially re -written to describe trade practice regulations.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Contents:
Issues relating to the history and purpose of alcohol regulation:
1. Aren't our alcohol regulations antiquated? Weren't they designed to prevent organized crime and other
problems of Prohibition?
2. Why do we need regulations to balance our alcohol market systems?
3. Since alcohol is a legal product, why can't it be sold like orange juice or any other legal product?
4. What are some real-world examples of what happened when alcohol was deregulated?
How our regulatory system works:
5. What does a good alcohol regulatory system look like?
6. Why are some states in the liquor business? What happens when a state privatizes?
7. Why are beer, wine and spirits regulated differently?
8. What are the benefits of the three-tier system of alcohol control?
9. Isn't alcohol regulation bad for business? Shouldn't we loosen alcohol regulations to help local
business?
Individual system elements:
10. Since the recession, all Americans expect good values, so what's the problem with lower prices for
alcohol?
11. Why shouldn't alcohol be more convenient for customers to buy?
12. What is the problem with allowing more stores to sell alcohol?
13. Why are there special hours for alcohol sales? Why do some states prohibit alcohol sales on Sunday
or holidays?
Revenue and safety:
14. Can't we save taxpayers some money by eliminating the liquor cops and using local law enforcement
or state police instead?
15. Why don't we have problems with fake alcohol or tax revenue loss?
16. What are trade practice regulations and why do we need them for alcohol?
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
am'" Issue Brief #1:
for a
fiesithy CO
Arent our alcohol regulations antiquated? Weren't
1 they designed to prevent organized crime and other
problems of Prohibition?
Today's alcohol regulations were primarily designed to prevent problems which
occurred before Prohibition. As Historian W.J. Rorabaugh reminds us, "For generations,
Americans had been heavy drinkers, and by 1900 saloons were identified with political
corruption, prostitution, gambling, crime, poverty and family destruction." Prior to
Prohibition alcohol was sold in a free-market scenario with little regulation. National
manufacturers controlled the industry and owned retail saloons—called "tied houses"
where almost all alcohol was consumed. To compete, each national company saturated
neighborhoods with multiple outlets which were often located near factories to attract
workers. Aggressive promotions encouraged high volume consumption and money was
used to dissuade politicians from crack -downs.
Most of our alcohol regulations are designed to prevent companies from dominating local markets by
heavily promoting large amounts of cheap alcohol. That is a very modern concern given the propensity of
large corporations to do that with other commodities and to do that in countries where alcohol can be sold in
virtual free-market scenarios.
The lessons from Prohibition are different. A primary lesson is that extreme measures applicable to
the entire country with very little flexibility do not work. Second, laws must have public support to be
effective. As a result, our alcohol regulations are state -based, allowing for differences and for
experimentation.
Currently, our regulations enjoy a high level of support as evidenced in numerous surveys. Based on a
national survey, Alexander Wagenaar and his colleagues found that the "Results showed high levels of public
support for most alcohol control policies. Over 80% support restrictions on alcohol use in public places, such
as parks, beaches, concert venues, and on college campuses. Eighty-two percent support increased alcohol
taxes, provided the funds are used for treatment or prevention programs. Over 60% support alcohol advertising
and promotion restrictions, such as banning billboard advertising, banning promotion at sporting events, or
banning liquor and beer advertising on television."
"Those who cannot
remember the past are
condemned to repeat
it, it
George Santayana,
Reason in Common Sense,
The Life of Reason, V61.1.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #2:
Why do we need regulations to balance our alcohol
market systems?
The reason for regulations in the alcohol market is very simple: some common business practices can
produce social harm. These practices often work well for other products, but not for alcohol.
Consider this example of three typical business plan strategies:
1. Efforts to retain and increase purchases by customers who are "frequent buyers."
2. Discounts and promotions to gain new frequent buyer customers.
3. Advertising to young people to build a future customer base.
When applied to alcohol sales, such business practices would:
1. Increase sales to frequent buyers, including heavy drinkers and alcoholics.
2. Use volume discounts and incentives to encourage heavy use.
3. Market alcohol to youth, thus encouraging underage drinking.
Alcohol regulatory systems seek to achieve a healthy balance of business practices which keep prices
moderate: not too low to push consumption, not too high to push bootlegging or theft. They also make
products reasonably available for customers, prohibit promotions that foster heavy consumption and strictly
control sales to minors. These things are designed to foster moderation because we know from research that
moderation in consumption of alcohol avoids most problems. One should be skeptical of cries for a free
market environment with no regulations. A truly free-market, devoid of any rules at all, does not really exist
for any commodity; for alcohol, it would result in serious unintended consequences.
Estimates indicate the alcohol market includes:
• 17.5% underage drinkers
20+% adult abusive/dependent drinkers
10-20% of alcohol sold is consumed by underage drinkers
Archives of Pediatrics and Adolescent Medicine, 2006
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #3:
Since alcohol is a legal product, why can't it be sold like
orange juice or any other legal product?
Most "legal" products are regulated to protect the public's health and safety. In the US, food products
are regulated by the Food and Drug Administration to ensure that products are safe and that the contents match
their labels. When regulation is weak or sloppy, we are at risk of food poisoning, food -borne illnesses, fraudulent
packaging and other problems. For similar reasons, restaurants are regularly inspected locally to ensure that they
serve only safe and healthy products. Fines and other penalties are issued to those in violation. No one would
suggest that we should have no food regulations merely because the sale of food products is legal.
One highly regulated product in today's market is the automobile.
Regulations require that each car sold must contain a long list of equipment to
ensure its safety, fuel economy, and to reduce air pollution. Once you buy a car,
there are more regulations to follow, including those for proper use of children's
car seats, seat belts, safe driving speeds, and so on. Once again, no one would ever
suggest that we should eliminate regulations just because the automobile is a legal
product.
Cigarettes are highly regulated products that have some interesting parallels with
alcohol. While cigarettes are legal to buy and smoke, there are many restrictions on their
sale and use. You have to be 18 to purchase cigarettes. You may not smoke in most public" ~
places. And you may have to pay higher insurance fees if you are a smoker. We all know
that the reason behind these regulations is the great harm cigarettes can cause to the human
body, including to those who inhale passive smoke from others. Research has shown a
connection between cigarette smoke and cancer and many other health problems.
Alcohol is unique in that it is invariably harmful when used to excess. The Centers for Disease Control
and Prevention estimate that 88,000 deaths PER YEAR WERE ATTRIBUTED TO EXCESSIVE ALCOHOL
USED FROM 2006 — 2010. In 2013, drunk driving alone caused 10,076 deaths (this is a decrease from 2012 of
2.5%) and cost $49.8 billion. These data alone justify the need for significant regulation.
Although there are some situations where alcohol should not be used at all, alcohol can usually be
enjoyed if used in moderation. Alcohol regulations both encourage moderation and restrict excessive use. This
preserves individual choice while protecting public health and safety.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
amP' Issue Brief #4:
foroDOI
What are some real-world examples of what happened
when alcohol was deregulated?
The United Kingdom is today's best example, although the State of Washington recently passed a
ballot measure which will make it one of the least regulated states. Over time, we will be able to measure the
impact on public health and safety.
The United Kingdom deregulated over a long period of time with an increase in problems following
closely in the wake. It began in the 1960's with allowing all forms of alcohol in grocery stores. As
competition heated up, alcohol became cheaper and even more available. Closing hours and other controls
were abandoned. Today in the UK you can buy all forms of alcohol everywhere with few restrictions, 24
hours a day, 7 days a week; this "convenience" has caused a serious alcohol epidemic. For example, hospital
admissions for liver disease and acute intoxication have more than doubled over 10 years. Underage drinking
in the UK is almost twice the US rate.
1a.
8N... `ice'
6.000
000
2,000
0
Alcohol-related deaths In the United Kingdom, 1991-2012
* 450P 7*.,:p Ilk 7t Ilk * 71k� 11a,79 1% * 'Irk"? tir 11% 11% 11?,01 lk % % +7, abzo
Source.* UK Office for Nahmal Statistics
All of the last three prime ministers have had an alcohol strategy designed to curb problems.
However, only the current Prime Minister, David Cameron, has focused on what research Thomas Babour and
colleagues assert are the "strong strategies": restrictions on affordability, availability, accessibility as well as
drunk -driving deterrence measures. But strategies are often hard to put into practice. Cameron proposed both
a minimum price and a ban on multi -buy discounts. He advocated for greater enforcement and local control
over licensees with the ability to sanction. So far, minimum price has been shelved. Multi -buy bans were only
recently instituted. Local enforcement is stronger although consistent strong action in local areas takes time to
implement. Cameron also is relying on an industry "Responsibility Deal" to remove a portion of alcohol from
the market. Some of these measures are having an impact. According to the UK National Health Services
statistics, overall consumption has decreased and youth drinking has declined. Serious violence is also down
according to a study by Cardiff University. However, death and disease rates are the consequence of many
years of excessive alcohol use and they remain high.
Other countries have also suffered severe problems from alcohol deregulation and are now struggling
to re -regulate:
For more Information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #4: What are some real-world examples of what happened when alcohol
was deregulated? Continued
Finland: Since the early 1960s, Finland gradually liberalized alcohol regulations and cut taxes. As a
result, average consumption for those over age 15 increased fourfold - from 3 liters per capita in 1969 to 12
liters in 2004. In 1998, Finland decreased its excise duties for some alcohol products by 17%. Again in 2004, it
was dropped another 33% in an effort to compete with other European Union countries. In the case of each
tax cut, consumption rose by 10%. Alcohol problems rose in tandem. In 1995, alcohol-related mortality rose
by 14% and in 2004 by 20%. Also in 2004, deaths from liver disease increased by 30%. The pressure for
these changes came from the EU, which favored deregulation for alcohol and lower taxes.
Since 2004, Finland has done a "U-turn" and raised taxes four times in an effort to reduce harm. As a
result, total consumption is down by about 10 percent and alcohol-related deaths have decreased. Finland is
continuing to implement measures to curb problems. While Finland current prohibits ads for strong alcohol
beverages in public spaces and has a time ban for TV, they will prohibit advertising of "mild" alcoholic
beverage campaigns that involve games lotteries or contests and content in social media. They also have
instituted new import limits via "booze cruises."
Russia: Alcohol is a primary cause for drastically reduced life
expectancy for men. In Russia, where men are very heavy drinkers, life
expectancy for men is 63, versus 75 for women. Per capita consumption of =Russia has 500,000
alcohol is enormous — about 4 gallons. This is twice the level the World annual deaths due to alcohol.
Health Organizations considers the "danger level." The number of deaths is Alcohol poisoning kills more
staggering: an estimated 500,000 annually. President Putin is working to curb than 23,000 per year.
this problem with a series of tax increases (30% increase for vodka), penalties
for sales to minors, restrictions on where liquor can be sold, health warnings, and a ban on advertising.
According to Euromonitor, sales have decreased although some suspect that there has been a corresponding
increase in the illegal market. Nevertheless, according to an article in the Lancet, 25% of Russian men die
before age 55 which is an improvement over 37% in 2006. It will be difficult for President Putin to achieve
his goal of cutting consumption in half by 2020.
i►'�1 1"
r
"We have a problem in
New Zealand with the sale of really cheap
alcohol. Cheaper alcohol tends to be bought
more by harmful drinkers than moderate
drinkers and studies show that it is also
attractive to young people."
Alcohol Advisory Council Chief Executive
Gerard Vaughan
New Zealand: Loosened regulations in 1989 and
problems increased. Since that time there have been numerous
discussions, committees, and cries for re -regulation. In 2010, an
Alcohol Reform Bill was developed. In December 2012,
Parliament passed the reform bill which will allow communities
to regulate outlet density and hours / days of sale, increase the
drinking age, ban dangerous products and products appealing to
youth, limit the size and strength of alcohol and increase
penalties. An entire year was given to enact these new rules.
Indeed, re -regulation takes a very long time. Nonetheless, bars
are now stocking up on lower alcohol beer, wine and spirits and
citizens are concerned about lower alcohol limits for drivers
implemented in December 2014.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
tamp �'" Issue Brief #5:
f o A�G°h01.__
liesithy'
What does a good alcohol regulatory system look like?
Today we know a great deal about what works in alcohol regulation thanks to a large body of high-
quality research. The World Health Organization has done extensive review of this research and developed
recommendations on how best to regulate alcohol. The following chart presents many of those
recommendations in an easy -to -understand "alphabet" format:
Our greatest protection is an effective alcohol control system which addresses the
ABCs of regulation:
• Availability. Allows alcohol to be sold by the bottle and the drink, but limits
the number, location, types of alcohol products, and hours of outlets.
• No "Bargain Booze". Regulations balance prices, control price competition,
and restrict dangerous marketing and promotional practices.
• Children and Teens. Age restrictions protect young people from the serious
problems of underage drinking.
• Drunk Driving. Creates and enforces strict measures against drinking and
driving- sobriety checks, blood alcohol limits, driver's license suspension.
• Education and Enforcement. Uses the carrot of education (alcohol awareness
programs, "schools" for offenders) and the stick of enforcement (fines,
community service and jail) when education fails.
Source: Adapted from World Health Organization recommendations.
In a recent article in the American Journal of Preventive Medicine, "Efficacy and the Strength of
Evidence of U.S., Alcohol Control Policies," a highly respected team of experts rated 47 different policies on
their efficacy and strength of evidence in reducing binge drinking and alcohol -impaired driving among the
general population and among the youth population. The top ten policies in rank order were:
Alcohol excise taxes
State alcohol control systems
Bans on alcohol sales
Outlet density restrictions
Wholesale price restrictions
Retail price restrictions
ABCs (Alcohol Beverage Control agencies) present, functional, adequately staffed
Dram shop liability laws
Hours of sale restrictions
Alcohol consumption restricted in public
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief ##6:
Why are some states in the liquor business? What happens
when a state privatizes?
After Prohibition, eighteen of the states and a number of local governments adopted the "control
system", whereby a unit of state or local government owns all or part of the alcohol business in its jurisdiction.
This was done to prevent problems experienced previously with an unregulated market. Prior to Prohibition,
large alcohol companies were strongly profit driven and pushed retailers to sell alcohol aggressively to factory
workers, heavy drinkers and even to children. They used credit, volume discounts, and other inducements to
increase the sale and consumption of alcohol. This encouraged intoxication and created major social problems.
A Control System is designed to ensure that no one
will have a profit incentive to sell alcohol to people who
shouldn't drink, such as youth and intoxicated persons.
Several states, some local governments, most Canadian
provinces and some Northern European countries have some
version of a control system. Since the state takes the profit
from the sale of alcohol, it can then use those funds to offset
the costs to taxpayers of alcohol abuse. These costs are
substantial. According to the Centers for Disease Control and
Prevention, "... excessive alcohol consumption cost the United
States $223.5 billion in 2006, or about $1.90 per drink."
Conversion from a control to a license system is far
from simple and has consequences for public health and safety, revenue, and the local business markets.
Since Prohibition ended the "control states" have made many changes to their systems and most now allow
some private sector operation, especially at the retail level. However, only one of the 18 original "control
states" has completely converted to a private, license system. That gives us the opportunity to see how such a
conversion impacts a state's public health and safety as well as its alcohol business market.
Prices are higher under the new license system: If a
control state's business is eliminated, the only way to replace lost
revenue is to impose new, high taxes. The reason is that control
systems provide revenue through both business profit and tax
collection. So, you have to replace both. This is exactly what the
Washington ballot measure did. First, the, retail sales tax of 20.5%
and the $3.77 per liter taxes were retained. Then, two new "fees"
were added, a 10% distribution fee and a 17% retail fee. On top of
all of these taxes and fees, a private business adds "mark-up" for
their profit. As a result, the average price per liter of hard liquor
after taxes increased by almost $4: from $24.06 to $21.59 according
to the Washington State Department of Revenue.
Average price of a 1fter of spirit
$23._.
1 �.
$20.00
Before 1183After 1183
rr 4shr Liw Erol Board
Consumers got more outlets for spirits, but less variety: Outlets for spirits increased substantially
and sales hours were increased. Before privatization, there were 328 state and contract stores open a
maximum of 73 hours per week. After passage of Measure 1183, there were 1,425 stores open a maximum of
140 hours per week. Under the Control System, state stores carried a large variety of spirits products in
addition to wine. These stores were auctioned off to private parties who often did not have enough capital to
purchase and maintain a large inventory. This issue was compounded by the fact that they had to compete
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #6: Why are some states in the liquor business? What happens when a
state privatizes? Continued
with all the large grocery stores and new "big box"
liquor store chains that quickly entered the market.
Many of the small stores quickly went out of business.
Grocery stores typically cleared a few shelves to stock
spirits which meant their selection was primarily a few
of the best selling products. Thus a consumer that
only buys the "best sellers" got a lot of convenience,
but anyone interested in unique products or greater
variety would need to find a large, chain liquor store
that stocked a substantial inventory.
Short-term revenue collections are artificially high thanks to a one-time fee assessed on
wholesalers of $105 million. Whether revenue will continue to be high enough to equal what the state got
under the old system remains to be seen. The legislature is heavy pressure to reduce the "fees" because the
small liquor stores are having a hard time competing. They have already made some changes and may make
more. Costco wrote the ballot measure to eliminate any barriers to large-scale purchasing directly from
suppliers at discount. Small independent stores don't have the funds to purchase large quantities, so have
difficulty competing. Many went out of business quickly.
Revenue aolkw#lons from various souroos in mlgirons of dollars
U 2012
N 2012
257.6
includes one time
flee of
an
23.5 93.9 •31.7
�2.:3 {includes auction proceeds,
tobacco seizure. penalties
and aider income
Beer Tax Wine Tax License Feet's Other
.+�'Di1t' C ft -q fngtM SWO t OWF CWM BWrdV UO' ACP" tar 22 t 2 a crd 2013
Local markets are dominated by large, national companies that stifle competition: As one might
expect, Costco wrote the ballot measure to favor large, national chains. Retailers with more than 101000
square feet can now obtain retail licenses. As noted earlier, smaller stores have great difficulty competing with
these large entities and many have failed. The wholesale market was quickly captured by the two largest
national wholesalers who gained 93% market share. Small, local wineries and distillers have greater difficulty
getting their products to market in this kind of a market.
High theft rates became an immediate public safety
problem, but other social impacts will take time to measure.
Given the high price, liquor became an attractive item for shoplifters
including organized gangs. Theft instances skyrocketed requiring
legislation to require better security. Privatization usually results in
increased problems with alcohol due to greater availability and
higher consumption. Research on previous instances of
privatization convinced the Centers for Disease Control's Task
Force on Community Preventive Services to recommend against
further privatization. However, impacts on underage drinking,
alcohol abuse, alcohol-related disease and other social ills take time
to measure. Therefore, we will not know the true impact for some
time.
"I think it's the dumbest thing
we ever did in our state," said
retiring Washington Liquor
Control Board chair Sharon
Foster. She blames higher
prices and increased shoplifting
of alcohol, especially by minors,
i-� 4
oil ills vot,er-apptoved IIlove.
KING 5 News, Dec. 8, 2014
For more informations www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
3.0
r(
X b/30/10 1
cr"ery
beerlwine
Sp its Retalter
Sectile
specialty
with all the large grocery stores and new "big box"
liquor store chains that quickly entered the market.
Many of the small stores quickly went out of business.
Grocery stores typically cleared a few shelves to stock
spirits which meant their selection was primarily a few
of the best selling products. Thus a consumer that
only buys the "best sellers" got a lot of convenience,
but anyone interested in unique products or greater
variety would need to find a large, chain liquor store
that stocked a substantial inventory.
Short-term revenue collections are artificially high thanks to a one-time fee assessed on
wholesalers of $105 million. Whether revenue will continue to be high enough to equal what the state got
under the old system remains to be seen. The legislature is heavy pressure to reduce the "fees" because the
small liquor stores are having a hard time competing. They have already made some changes and may make
more. Costco wrote the ballot measure to eliminate any barriers to large-scale purchasing directly from
suppliers at discount. Small independent stores don't have the funds to purchase large quantities, so have
difficulty competing. Many went out of business quickly.
Revenue aolkw#lons from various souroos in mlgirons of dollars
U 2012
N 2012
257.6
includes one time
flee of
an
23.5 93.9 •31.7
�2.:3 {includes auction proceeds,
tobacco seizure. penalties
and aider income
Beer Tax Wine Tax License Feet's Other
.+�'Di1t' C ft -q fngtM SWO t OWF CWM BWrdV UO' ACP" tar 22 t 2 a crd 2013
Local markets are dominated by large, national companies that stifle competition: As one might
expect, Costco wrote the ballot measure to favor large, national chains. Retailers with more than 101000
square feet can now obtain retail licenses. As noted earlier, smaller stores have great difficulty competing with
these large entities and many have failed. The wholesale market was quickly captured by the two largest
national wholesalers who gained 93% market share. Small, local wineries and distillers have greater difficulty
getting their products to market in this kind of a market.
High theft rates became an immediate public safety
problem, but other social impacts will take time to measure.
Given the high price, liquor became an attractive item for shoplifters
including organized gangs. Theft instances skyrocketed requiring
legislation to require better security. Privatization usually results in
increased problems with alcohol due to greater availability and
higher consumption. Research on previous instances of
privatization convinced the Centers for Disease Control's Task
Force on Community Preventive Services to recommend against
further privatization. However, impacts on underage drinking,
alcohol abuse, alcohol-related disease and other social ills take time
to measure. Therefore, we will not know the true impact for some
time.
"I think it's the dumbest thing
we ever did in our state," said
retiring Washington Liquor
Control Board chair Sharon
Foster. She blames higher
prices and increased shoplifting
of alcohol, especially by minors,
i-� 4
oil ills vot,er-apptoved IIlove.
KING 5 News, Dec. 8, 2014
For more informations www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #7:
Why are beer, wine and spirits regulated differently?
After Prohibition, both a new alcohol marketplace and a new regulatory system had to be created. Since
state legislators knew little about alcohol markets, all states relied more or less—on a study called Toward
Liquor Control by R. B. Fosdick and A.L. Scott. This work was sponsored by John D. Rockefeller, a leading
entrepreneur of the day. The two authors studied alcohol regulatory systems in other countries and developed a
set of recommendations designed to foster public safety by eliminating violence in public drinking places and
encouraging moderation among those who wanted to drink. To encourage moderate consumption, they
recommended two types of licenses that would encourage consumption of "light alcohol products" in single -
serving containers and discourage consumption of more potent products.
The first license type was for retailers who sold "lighter" beverages, which usually meant 3.2% beer
because Americans did not drink much wine. The idea was to have widespread availability for the sale of these
"light" products. The new approach meant that beer would no longer be sold primarily in kegs and buckets, as it
was before Prohibition, but in single -serving size cans and bottles. These smaller size containers were meant to
limit intake or, at least, give the consumer some idea of how much they were drinking. The license for these
stores usually allowed the sale of other products, so the grocery store became the most common type of licensee.
The second type of license (or state -operated store) was the liquor store—often referred to as a "package
store." There were fewer of these stores, their hours were curtailed, they did not permit entrance to those
underage, and they were the only places where hard liquor and high -alcohol wine or beer could be sold.
Generally, these licenses did not permit extensive sale of other products. The idea was that licensees would
become specialists in the proper selling of alcohol. Moreover, they would not be able to sell alcohol very
cheaply because they had no other products from which to make up profits lost by deep discounting.
Grocery Store
Liquor Store
- Low alcohol beer in single
serving containers (3.2%0 0 6%}
- Light wine (often 12% - 13%)
- Spirits and other higher alcohol content products
-Other products such as groceries
< Items Sold >
' Primarily sell alcohol. Loss leader is difficult
available
without non -alcohol products to sell. Promotion /
- Sale of alcohol not necessary to
advertising sometimes controlled.
be a profitable store
- Outlets widely available
< Outlet
-Outlets limited by state quotas, local ordinance
Density >
or state ownership
-Greater days /hours of sale
< Hours of
-Limited hours / days of sales: generally no
Sale >
Sunday, holiday or late-night sales
- Customers of any age
< Minors >
- Customers must be 21 +. Some states cite minors
for being in store.
- Usually clerks can be under 21
- High turnover provides Fess
- Clerks must be 21 +.
expertise in regulatory
< Employees >
- Mandatory training in alcohol regulation is
requirements to avoid sales to
common.
minors and intoxicated persons.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #7: Why are beer, wine and spirits regulated differently? Continued
Pressure to move from tight to light control for all alcohol products.
The original dual license system has eroded in several ways:
• The alcohol content of "Lighter" products has increased. While 3.2% beer is still produced, the alcohol
content of beer now averages around 4-5%, with some craft brews much higher. Many states have
increased the allowable percentage of alcohol in beer sold in stores to as high as 8-12 percent. The
percentage of alcohol in wine has increased from around 12% to 13-14%, with some varieties much
higher.
• The place of wine in our markets has changed. For some time after Prohibition, few Americans drank
wine. That has changed as about 1/3 of Americans now drink wine as their primary alcoholic
beverage. And, the availability of wine has increased as more states have allowed it to be sold in
grocery and convenience stores.
• New products, many of which appeal primarily to youth, are sold in grocery and convenience stores
because they are "malt -based" and qualify as beer, or they are "wine -based" and qualify as wine.
Some of these products are sold in large containers --over 20 ounces with 12% alcohol.
• Several states have allowed hard liquor and other high -alcohol content products to be sold in grocery
and convenience stores without the additional controls that liquor stores have including the use of self-
service systems. These systems are lightly staffed which can increase theft as well as sale of alcohol
to youth and intoxicated persons.
• Hours and days of sale have been extended; and many states are moving toward allowing the sale of
all forms of alcohol for extended hours, seven days a week.
0
Beer and Wine 9)?
Beer, Wine and spirits
None
Mote. Grac+y 140f cxdriats /t►* +mit adoahok
tegurenwft Lodi iams w M8 sale d alwhok
evnf;vm nay UPI*
Grocery Store Sales - 2014
* Colorado -- 1-7,* f a
Michigan - Mwa haw- adequate physical 0ani
phial - tit, witie, and mixed ty-veiage-# in
tb Texas - st tali ow u-tclinwirwats for a
ap;"u *We tris tyl* and 84, - of buvtteu.
waw col dailwots tr.•t Waif -protest s conn. mptVan
{,;wkaW shore t,"mol to -A41 rifiimdhiq
* Nofiida - ,ri119inKety 5iows may sett beet and
zo-e lremttnted. Agovcy oulkts may .also sell
tirnited ttnam arca j(p' of eantployees
wine, a grixely/ Stole vatth a separate er4u xe
Annesota 1.2% t ►r.
sptrittutis liquoi.
and exit Im its sfxirits wtion may sell spirits
0 Utah - 3.2% beet.
Kssissippi t (l ess than 8% by ht) #lc
Okiat'toma - 3.2% beet.
'Idaho - Gtixevy stores may Seu beet, wire.
Light One Itess than W- by wx iahti.
0 Vermont - Spirits only at a fquor agency
and iow tyro f spitits up to 14% andalcohol
• Oregon - Beer, wine, and cider ato; r nim -d
store within the gictcety store.
and ports, tit ortitt-, and madeitas up to 21% If
• New Hampshire - tis twit t. at9"tlt titre ti.aiv (if
a giotcer'y stme is .a %:ontr aclor of tate kJaho
marra arta products.
IL Rennsyttaama Onty by a state wine and spirift3
C miming Watkoh ok products must tai'
State Liquor Divnion, It may also sell high
strlapr rating within a gtdacery state,
sold in a sc paraw trsr m.
ptcacsf distilled spirits.
New Jersey - The ; of gtoc .;aios ru" be the
In tiAtp buoness. the Sateof akeholic hewta-
0 Tonnessee - Lav a th-.s have the 044100 ID
* WaShinfjtOn - 144, 1 sv rW. s alga SID
't taiitw - ', mutt Wv€rage .
rs OWS4 itr rtlerety itwkk-ntaltnd mAxytdin4le
4ppiv w win,- salt's in qjm4-ry tAmes,
allfmwdirl stfule"t+vis lttWt ulume to t.
tt*1010.
• Mbryiand - AtcnW4 sah,s in supetrrtarketsate
prohlbitc-d except Ihow that h", aeon
gtarfat-hw9 in
Source: National Alcohol Beverage Control Association
For more information: www.healthyalcoholinarket.com
Issue Brief #8:
What are the benefits of a three-tier system of alcohol
control?
The United States has a unique system that requires alcohol to be sold through three separate market
tiers: manufacturer/supplier, wholesaler, and retailer.
Generally, the tiers must be separately licensed and owned, independent of one another. This prevents
marketplace domination by large companies that seek to greatly increase the sale of alcohol through aggressive
sales practices, or by controlling the entire alcohol distribution chain, from manufacturer to consumer.
Before Prohibition, large manufacturers dominated the alcohol marketplace by owning chains of retail
establishments. They pushed the retailers to sell very aggressively to make high profits. A modern version of
marketplace domination can be found in the United Kingdom, where four large grocery chains dominate the
market and sell alcohol so cheaply that it has fueled an epidemic of alcohol-related illnesses. It is also
believed that this domination has caused many traditional pubs to close since more people are drinking cheap
alcohol at home.
The tiered system in the US keeps prices balanced, prohibits or inhibits aggressive sales practices, and
allows both small and large operators to be profitable. This system also uses checks and balances from one
tier to another to enforce many provisions, and the middle tier is used to collect taxes and track products (a
function the government would otherwise have to perform at extra cost to the taxpayers).
Below is a general illustration of how the three-tier system works. Each state does it somewhat
differently and all are subject to some federal regulations preventing ownership or financial ties between
manufacturers and retailers. A publication that features just two of the benefits of the three tiered system
called, "Safe and Sound". How the three-tier system of U.S. alcohol regulations helps ensure safe products
and protects against revenue loss, is available at healthyalcoholmarket.com.
r
the Three -Tier Alcohol
rol System Supports a
hy Alcohol Marketplace
Manufacturers
Distributors/
Wholesalers
The •
3 -Tier --
Regulatory Retailers-''' .
System
• Financial Independence prevents business practices which
promote increased and high-volume consumption through
price reductions. (Ownership prohibited between sectors)
• Functional Independence protects the integrity of the three-
tier system by prohibiting ways to circumvent it. (One sector
can't perform function of another)
• Price Regulations prevent increased consumption that
would occur by selling large quantities of very cheap product.
(Uniform pricing, ban on volume discounts
• Promotion and Advertising Regulations prevent business
practices that target high -drinking groups and promote
volume consumption.
• Tax Collection provides for an efficient tax collection
system.
• Product Tracking prevents sale of tainted and counterfeit
product.
• Age Restrictions prevent sales to underage youth.
• Availability Limits reduce consumption, social problems
and burden on law enforcement.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #9:
Isn't alcohol regulation bad for business? Shouldn't we
loosen alcohol regulations to help local business?
The answer is generally no to both questions. In fact, for most businesses alcohol regulation offers some real benefits.
While the system sometimes seems cumbersome and a business owner may wish for a free market system, most free markets
end up benefiting only a few large companies. The states' alcohol regulatory systems are designed to foster alcohol moderation,
prevent underage drinking and other problems AND to allow the owners of all sizes and types of businesses to make a
reasonable profit. Much has been said about the public safety issues, but policy -makers should also consider the following
benefits to business:
The Three -Tier System prevents market domination: Look at the soda pop shelf in your grocery store and you
have an idea of what alcohol might look like in a deregulated environment. The soda space is occupied by two major
companies. The alcohol regulatory system requires that alcohol be sold through three separate, independent tiers: manufacturer,
wholesaler and retailer. In addition, most states require price policies that level the playing field. For example, uniform price
laws require the wholesaler to sell their products at the same price to all retailers. This means the large corporation can't get a
better deal than the local mom-and-pop store. It also keeps prices from going so low that "bargains" encourage people to drink
more.
Regulations reduce some costs of doing business: For most
commodities, large grocery stores require slotting fees; that is, payments made to
the grocer to assure products a place on their shelves. Manufacturers and
wholesalers may also have to stock shelves, pay for advertising, provide
promotional point-of-sale items, and buy refrigerated units. These are generally
illegal for alcohol products. If controls are removed, small players would not be
able to get their product to market without paying for these "extras."
Freedom from price wars and other forms of market volatility:
Most states have several ways of keeping the price of alcohol balanced, i.e. not low enough to encourage volume consumption,
nor so high as to encourage bootlegging and illegal importation. Laws such as bans on volume discounts and selling below cost
keep prices reasonably stable. Without these laws, large corporations with huge economic buying power would undercut
small usually local businesses, and possibly put them out of operation.
Product tracking protects against unwarranted business ruination: Even the best manufacturing companies can
make a mistake that creates a tainted batch or product. In today's market, even minor problems with product quality can ruin a
company or disrupt a commodity market. This is much less likely to happen in the alcohol marketplace because wholesalers are
required to track every bottle and can. With this system, a problem batch or product can be quickly identified and removed
from the retail shelf. This minimizes harm and can save a business.
Predictability: Because the regulations keep the alcohol marketplace balanced and free from extreme volatility,
business owners can have confidence in their investments. Predictability reduces risks and makes business planning easier.
Compliance with regulations helps prevent neighborhood and community problems: Most business people find
that a clean and safe neighborhood is good for business. Alcohol regulations help. By preventing sales to underage youth and
intoxicated people, fewer neighborhood problems are likely.
Policy -makers should consider these points very carefully when alcohol deregulation measures are under review.
While being free of regulations may sound good, the reality is often very different. Remember that the change in rules must
apply to all licensees. For example, if the law requiring uniform prices is abandoned, wholesalers would then be allowed to give
some retailers special prices. Who would get that special price and how would that impact local businesses? Chances are that
large, global corporations would be the only ones getting the best deals because they alone can buy a very large volume of
product. Thus, a so-called "free market" would only benefit a few companies.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #10:
Since the recession, Americans expect good values, so
what's the problem with lower prices for alcohol?
The answer is simple: lower prices increase drinking and the problems that
come with drinking. Price is one of the most powerful tools available to reduce
social problems with alcohol. Consider this evidence: a team of researchers from
the University of Florida reviewed over 100 separate studies that had over 1000
statistical estimates of price versus consumption. The showing was very consistent,
demonstrating that alcohol taxes and prices impact the level of drinking.
For Americans alcohol prices have seen primarily modest increases except
for prices in bars and restaurants where they have gone up steadily and now
represent a major difference between prices for at home versus away from home.
This likely reflects the hyper -competitive environment of the grocery business today
and the extensive use of price reductions to draw customers into a store.
300
W
91
Consumer prices, 1978-2013
"When prices go
down, people drink
more, and when
prices go up,
people drink less,
Alexander C.
Wagenaar, Ph.D.,
Professor of
Epidemiology and
Health Policy
Research at the
University of Florida
Prices for alcohol to consume at home
Noma Prices for alcohol away from home
Prices for all: foods
All Ars d+ T.� � � � Qf # l
Source.,- Af u-
Bureau of Labor Slaftfics
Offering cheap prices for alcohol facilitates excess consumption in various ways. For example,
underage drinkers are price -sensitive and generally drink to intoxication. They are the consumers who likely
purchase inexpensive products in stores since they can't readily drink in bars. The rising gap also fosters pre -
drinking practices which means drinkers may be impaired before and after going out.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #11:
Why shouldn't alcohol be more convenient for customers
to buy?
Today, large national chain grocers are arguing for loosening regulations in order to provide greater
customer convenience. They argue that customers shouldn't have to go to several other stores for their
alcohol. They should be able to have a "one-stop shop."
The first consideration for any change in alcohol regulation should be its impact on public health and
safety, not customer convenience. Additional convenience for alcohol consumers would mean more stores,
longer opening hours, and more forms of alcohol in more locations. A review of the research indicates that all
of these things increase consumption, which leads to more social problems. This, in turn, puts a large and
costly burden on social services and law enforcement. When regulations are relaxed, most of the additional
alcohol sold is purchased by heavy drinkers, a category which also includes youth.
The fact is that today's shoppers routinely shop at several different stores during a given week. While large
chains may want customers to only shop at their "one-stop shop" store, customers just don't do that.
According to Business Insider reporter Hayley Peterson, "The grocery industry in the U.S. is undergoing some of
the most dramatic changes since supermarkets emerged in the 1940s. Whereas a single store once served all of shoppers'
food and beverage needs, consumers are now buying groceries across more than a dozen retail channels." Just letting all
big chains sell alcohol won't necessarily improve convenience.
A second fact to be considered is that most citizens are
not regular consumers of alcohol as revealed in. a survey by the
Centers for Disease Control and Prevention.
As one can see, 35% of Americans do not drink at
all, and another 13% drink only a few times a year. In
addition, 31 % have three drinks or fewer per week, which
means they buy less than a six-pack of beer or one bottle
of wine a week. This leaves moderate drinkers (1-2 drinks
per day) and heavy drinkers (3 or more drinks per day) as
regular alcohol customers. Thus, the expanded availability
of alcohol would benefit only 20% of the population at
most, but the increased social and law enforcement costs
would be borne by every taxpayer.
Given these statistics, one should ask: "Is it
sensible to inconvenience 20% of the population to protect
the other 80% from the social ills and law enforcement
costs that occur when problem drinkers have unlimited
access to alcohol?"
As it is not illegal to be a heavy drinker, regulating the availability of alcohol remains a highly
effective way to control problem drinking. Such regulations have the added benefit of being minimally
intrusive for the rest of society because they affect just a small percentage of the population.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #12:
What is the problem with allowing more stores to sell
alcohol?
We've always known that a neighborhood saturated with bars, liquor stores and other alcohol outlets
can be a recipe for disaster. Now we have research that confirms this idea. The Centers for Disease Control
and Prevention hosts an independent task force that reviews credible research. That group, the Community
Preventative Services Task Force, recommends using regulatory authority, such as licensing and zoning, to
limit outlet. Their research shows a positive link between the number of establishments selling alcohol, over-
consumption and related harms.
Here are some examples of specific research
findings: Two Indiana University professors reported on
their analysis of crime and outlet density in Cincinnati. They
found that off -premise outlets were responsible for one in
four simple assaults and one in three aggravated assaults. In
another study of eight college communities, E. R. Weitzman
and her team from the Harvard School of Public Health
found that alcohol outlet density was correlated with heavy
drinking, frequent drinking, and drink -related problems,
particularly among women, underage students, and students
who did not drink prior to coming to college.
{
Ve
�.`1
il
Using alcohol regulation or local zoning to reduce outlet
concentration can be complicated. It usually involves a process of
establishing problem areas by mapping crime and nuisance incidents
and locations of licenses. These are the areas where caution is needed
when considering applications for new licenses. This is particularly
true for the types of licenses that generate the most police calls, i.e.
places where alcohol constitutes the bulk of sales. In Glendale,
Arizona, police found that the top six convenience stores for police
calls cost the city $39,000 a year. Four of those six had over 1,000
calls to police in just one year. While most licensees are responsible,
adding many more outlets can overwhelm law enforcement. There are
helpful resources available to guide local communities in dealing with
this issue. The Center for Alcohol Marketing and Youth (camy.org)
and the Community Anti -Drug Coalitions of America (cadca.org) have
an action guide for use by local coalitions.
T !� !1f41rnY, i4t LJ A [� 41 7 \ lls�t st n�1 rra sl c 'cn reisom — A—. 6�4-1_ f � 4 t'- � l
V11ul1l.inLl� 1 r�v�nLl�' e 0 1 v Ik_•VJ 1 a6n 1 vi �� Y �vvliII111U U1*5 L>>� i�sE ui I"Cgl,llalol y d'l.lLtll�i'Ity e.g.,
through licensing and zoning) to limit alcohol outlet density on the basis of sufficient evidence of a
positive association between outlet density and excessive alcohol consumption and related harms."
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief ##13:
Why are there special hours for alcohol sales? Why
do some states prohibit alcohol sales on Sunday or
holidays?
Research shows that when regulations change to allow more hours and days of sale, alcohol problems
get worse. In fact, a national task force has generally recommended that these types of limits be retained. The
Task Force on Community Preventive Services states, "On the basis of strong evidence of effectiveness, the
Task Force recommends maintaining existing limits on the days on which alcoholic beverages are sold as one
strategy for the prevention of excessive alcohol consumption and related harms." This evidence came from
the Task Force's assessment of studies on the impact of repeal of these limits. The Task Force is an
independent, nonfederal group that is developing a Guide to Community Prevention Services with the support
of the US Department of Health and Human Services.
Generally, research has found that the more widely available alcohol
is in a community, the more problems that community has with alcohol.
The Task Force, which conducted a systematic review of research, noted
that removal of days of sale for off -premise licensees (grocery and
convenience stores) resulted in small increases in alcohol consumption and
motor vehicle fatalities. Removal of such limits for on -premise licensees
(bars, taverns, restaurants) was associated with substantial increases in
motor vehicle related harm and smaller increases in consumption.
Regarding hours of sale, the Task Force states, "On the basis of
sufficient evidence of effectiveness, the Task Force recommends
maintaining existing limits on the hours during which alcoholic beverages
are sold at on -premise outlets as another strategy for preventing alcohol-
related harms." It found that increasing hours of sale by two or more hours
for on -premise places resulted in significant increases in vehicle crash
injuries, emergency room admissions, and alcohol-related assault and injury.
Changes of less than two hours showed inconsistent results, and there were
no studies of off -premises hour changes to review.
The Community
Preventative Services
Task Force on
"recommends
maintaining existing
limits of the days on
which alcoholic
beverages are sold as
one strategy for the
prevention of excessive
alcohol consumption
and related harms."
The United Kingdom has generally abandoned limits on hours and days of sale, now allowing alcohol
to be sold 24 hours a day. The theory was that bar violence would decrease when there was no "last call" for
drinks, and patrons could exit any time of the day or night. This regulation is now widely recognized as a
failure because patrons drink for more hours per bar visit, and police and emergency medical resources are
experiencing greater stress and utilization. A recent study of bar violence in Manchester found that staggered
closing hours alone had no impact on violence.
A final consideration is that of police resources. Laws cannot be effective with little or no
enforcement. As more hours and days of sale are added, this puts a strain on enforcement agencies that work
to prevent illegal sales to minors, sales to intoxicated patrons, disturbances at bars and drunk driving. All of
these things increase with longer hours, creating dangers for our communities.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
art, Issue Brief #14:
Can't we save taxpayers some money by eliminating the
liquor cops and using local law enforcement or state poli
ce
-- instead?
Today, states are under great pressure to reduce budgets. All government agencies are vulnerable.
However, budget changes which result in greatly reduced alcohol law enforcement can have serious
consequences.
There are some disturbing trends. According to former Michigan regulator Pat Gagliardi, the burden
for liquor enforcement has increased significantly. The number of licensees per liquor enforcement agent went
up 22% from 2003 to 2012. While some states added staff, more of them decreased it. Some states have taken
drastic steps to downgrade liquor law enforcement, adding this function to already burdened local or state law
enforcement, or merging with other agencies such as lottery or tobacco.
All states should carefully review these kinds of proposals to clearly understand the losses and gains.
While merging liquor enforcement with a criminal justice or other regulatory agency may gain some
administrative efficiency, it may result in less effective liquor law enforcement. Here are some potential
impacts of such a measure:
Loss of effective industry partnerships: Regulating
the alcohol industry is very different from enforcing criminal
laws. It requires an effective and active working relationship
with the regulated community. The reason is that major
responsibilities for prevention of problems are placed on the
shoulders of licensees. These include stopping sales to minors
and intoxicated persons. For these functions the retail licensee is
the front line of defense. Substantial responsibilities are also
required of licensed wholesalers. They collect the excise tax.
They must track every bottle and can to guard against fake and
tainted products. When a damaged product is identified, they
must quickly remove it from the market. In some states,
wholesalers are required to implement pricing regulations to
prevent price wars. Such price practices invariably increase
consumption, particularly among young people.
Low priority for liquor enforcement: Local law enforcement naturally puts a priority on serious
criminal offenses such as murder, robbery, rape and assault. While law enforcement is keenly aware that a
large portion of those crimes are committed under the influence of alcohol, they are often overwhelmed with
the need to respond to specific criminal incidents. In many instances, they have sustained recent budget cuts,
are already over -burdened with responsibility, and don't have much capacity for additional functions.
Loss of effective means to control underage drinking and intoxication: Public health officials
have consistently recommended that enforcement of liquor laws be strengthened in order to reduce commercial
availability of alcohol to minors. Programs to reduce public intoxication and bar violence are critical to
community livability. While local law enforcement has often been active in conducting compliance checks to
reduce underage drinking, the alcohol beverage control agencies have been the statewide leaders that facilitate
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #14: Can't we save taxpayers some money by eliminating the liquor cops
and using local law enforcement or state police instead? Continued
partnerships with local and state enforcement. They often establish standards, conduct training for local
enforcement, publicize results to increase deterrence, and track effectiveness. Many beverage control agencies
have active programs to deal with problem bars and to reduce public intoxication. While law enforcement can
do these things also, the alcohol beverage agency can use the liquor license as leverage to gain compliance.
All laws must be enforced to some degree. To allow lawlessness is an affront to the honest businessperson.
And, sometimes only a little enforcement is needed. When coupled with publicity, a little enforcement goes a
long way to deterring future offenses.
Loss of efforts to educate licensee community: If we expect
licensees to comply with regulations and perform their duties, they must
know what they are, why they exist and specifically what actions are
required. For example, retailers must know how to judge age, check ID
and effectively refuse sales to minors. They should be able to spot
obvious fake ID and inform law enforcement when there are thefts and
obvious situations in which adults furnish alcohol to minors. Without
these actions, the prohibition against sales to minors would be quite
ineffective. Bar personnel must know the laws concerning service to
intoxicated persons, be able to spot signs of intoxication and effectively
refuse additional sales. In order for these functions to be performed
routinely and effectively, there needs to be ongoing communication and
educational efforts.
Loss of Cooperation and Compliance: No system of law or
regulation can work by intensely scrutinizing and policing all laws and all
those subject to regulation. It would be too big of a job requiring
enormous resources. All systems from criminal law to child labor
regulations count on compliance by most parties. The partnership
between regulatory enforcement and the regulated community, which
seeks to maximize compliance, is very cost-effective and saves taxpayer
dollars.
In a study of the efficacy and strength of forty seven alcohol policies, a team of researchers ranked
"ABCs present, functional, adequately staffed" seventh highest in terms of impacting binge drinking and drunk
driving.
For more information; www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #15:
Why don't we have problems with fake alcohol or tax
revenue loss?
Have you ever noticed that there are no stories about counterfeit alcohol in the United States? Did you
know that tax collections for alcohol excise tax are almost 100%? Indeed, these are major problems elsewhere.
In February 2011, the BBC was quoted as saying, "Up to a quarter of licensed premises in some parts of the
UK have been found to have counterfeit alcohol for sale." It was also noted that alcohol fraud costs the UK
about 1 billion pounds per year in lost revenue. (Feb. 15, 2011, "Fake alcohol on sale in many UK off -
licenses".) More recently, over 35 people died in the Czech Republic because counterfeit spirit products
containing methanol were distributed to stores in that country. The government had to ban spirit sales for a
period of time to ensure safety. It caused substantial loss to business and in tax revenue. Problems with fake
alcohol have occurred in Turkey, Ecuador, China and India.
One of the reasons for our good fortune is the strength
of our "three-tier regulatory system." The United States has a
closed distribution system which prevents adulterated and
contaminated products from reaching the consumer. In the U.S.
we require that alcohol go from a licensed manufacturer to a
licensed distributor to a licensed retailer. The businesses in
each tier are separately licensed and no manufacturer can own
or have a financial interest in a retailer. Many states also
prohibit ownership between all three tiers.
Distributors have major regulatory responsibilities.
They collect the excise tax on alcohol and are responsible for
tracking all products. Because of the tracking system, spoiled''"''
or recalled products can be quickly identified and pulled. An
added benefit is the fact that these regulations are not
expensive to enforce. Because distributors visit retailers regularly, they notice a product that they did not
supply. It is their obligation to immediately report such products to the regulatory agency. Under this system, it
would be very difficult for a retailer to systematically sell counterfeit or untaxed products. And, a distributor is
unlikely to jeopardize their license by offering a fake product to a retailer.
In a report on the fake alcohol situation in the United States, former Chief Counsel for the United
States Alcohol and Tobacco Tax and Trade Bureau Robert M. Tobiassen cites a
cultural respect for the rule of law and lack of corruption in governance and a
strong regulatory systems at the state and federal level as major reasons for the lack
of fake alcohol problems. He also notes that our competitive free-market system
5 provides alcohol at all price points which dilute the incentive for dealing in fake
alcohol products. However, he indicates that "the production and distribution of
cox moonshine poses a public health risk that is real and may be underestimated by
consumers, emergency medicalpersonnel, and others."
-; genc y
As the United Kingdom and other countries grapple with alcohol regulation, the lessons learned by the
United States are under consideration. The United Kingdom has developed a registration process for
wholesalers. All wholesalers will be required to register and become subject to sanctions if they are found to
be dealing in fake or untaxed alcohol products. While lost revenue is a problem, the consequences of
consuming counterfeit alcohol can be quite serious. Illegal products often contain high levels of methanol.
Methanol is not fit for human consumption and can cause blindness or death. Public safety needs to be the first
consideration when considering changes to alcohol regulation.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Camfor hol
p � n
. T. Issue Brief #16:
\* What are trade practice regulations and why do we
.. need them for alcohol?
Trade practice regulations for alcohol are often referred to as "Prohibition -era measures" not relevant
to today's free-market system. But nothing could be further from the truth. The basic trade practice
regulations are not even unique to alcohol, but form the bedrock of our free market system. The reason is that
regulations are necessary to ensure the public gains the benefit of efficiencies, competition and innovation that
come with free-market systems. In free-market systems there is a tendency for one or more companies to
dominate and sometimes corruption sets in. Regulations, consistently and fairly enforced, can help prevent
these things. For example, we have seen major problems with corruption and market domination come with
lax regulatory enforcement of financial markets.
Trade practice regulation is even more important for the sale of products which can produce harm such
as alcohol, tobacco and now marijuana. Corruption, dishonest dealing and overly -aggressive sales can lead to
high underage use, as well as other public health and safety problems.
Trade practice basics: regulations impacting the US economy as a whole
Basic trade practice regulations focus on preventing these practices: price discrimination favoring
some purchasers over others, exclusive agreements, tying arrangements and mergers/acquisitions which reduce
market competition. These regulations are embodied in our national anti-trust laws including the Sherman and
Clayton Antitrust laws. Under those laws, the above -listed practices are "impermissible" because they work to
stifle competition. In 1936, the Robinson-Patman Act amended the Clayton Act to identify price
discrimination among equally -situated distributors as "anti-competitive."
Trade practices for alcohol: For alcohol, trade practices have the additional objectives of preventing
aggressive sales practices which induce high volume consumption. These practices include deep discounting,
price inducements for increased purchase, tied house arrangements and exclusive pay -to -play systems
(commercial bribery). These are the kinds of practices which created major social problems before
Prohibition. Here is how the regulations work:
Preventing price discrimination reduces alcohol abuse problems. Price is a very strong driver of
consumption; therefore, it is important to prevent the deep discounting practices which foster increases in
drinking rates particularly among youth. Our system does that in several ways:
• High volume, deep discounts are curtailed by requiring all products to be sold through a three -
tiered licensed system.
• "Same price for all" laws, common in many states, require wholesalers to sell all products for the
same price to all retailers. This levels the playing field for small and large operators and reduces
the incentive to engage in deep discounting.
• Prohibitions against selling below cost, again common in several states, prevent extreme price
reductions and price wars that generally induce greater consumption.
• A balanced market with many players provides sufficient competition to keep prices from going
too high. High prices can foster theft, bootlegging and other illegal practices.
Preventing a tied house means a manufacturer can't pay a retailer to purchase its products.
Tied house laws prevent a corrupt system where cash payments or other things of value are offered to a retailer
if that retailer will favor a particular product through special promotions, favorable placement, or carrying
products to the exclusion of others. Not only do tying arrangements reduce competition, but they often
involve aggressive sales tactics as the expectation for the payment is high profits. A system where products
get into a local market through payments, not through customer sales is no longer a "free market system", but
one that rewards dishonesty.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Issue Brief #16: What are trade practice regulations and why do we need them for
alcohol? Continued
Preventing exclusive business arrangements maintains healthy competition and reduces
problems of market domination. Exclusive arrangements occur when a retailer agrees to regularly purchase
a particular manufacturers products to the exclusion of other competitive products. These arrangements are
often called vertical integration because the manufacturer and retailer act as one entity. Such arrangements
stifle competition and innovation, but often lead to aggressive sales practices as the entity attempts to push
others out of the marketplace.
Federal law
Federal alcohol law includes several trade practice prohibitions. Those are found in the Federal
Alcohol Administration Act (27 United States Code, Chapter 8, Subchapter I, Section 205) and they define the
following as unfair competition and unlawful practices:
(a) Exclusive outlet- An exclusive outlet is a practice by which an industry member requires a retailer to
purchase its alcohol beverages.
(b) "Tied house" - A "tied house" is a practice whereby an industry member induces a retailer to purchase its
alcohol beverages.
(c) Commercial bribery - Commercial bribery is a practice whereby an industry member induces a
wholesaler or retailer to purchase its alcohol beverages.
There are also federal FAA laws regarding consignment sales, labeling and advertising. The TTB puts out
circulars from time to time to clarify these regulations.
State laws
State laws often repeat the federal prohibitions, include laws specific to a particular state and usually
define in some detail what constitutes a "thing of value", deceptive or prohibited practices. Sometimes these
laws are hard to understand and may seem unnecessary. And, sometimes it is hard to justify spending
enforcement resources on a licensee that has accepted free napkins or coasters from a supplier. However,
experience has shown that suppliers get very creative in trying to seek an advantage in licensed premises.
Usually, though not always, supplier representatives know they can't provide cash or large items such as TV's
free of charge, but might get away with a year's supply of napkins. Lack of enforcement for trade practices
can lead to a situation where one supplier starts providing inducements and it gets out of control to the point
where most suppliers are doing it. This happened in Arizona where large amounts of cash, gift cards, free
product, furniture and services were supplied to retailers as inducements to carry or promote particular
products. After an extensive investigation, fines were levied as well as agreements to work with liquor
authorities to change practices.
Wholesale and retail price restrictions are rated highly by alcohol researchers for effectiveness
in reducing binge drinking and drunk driving. Generally these policies restrict volume discounts and
other discount practices and prohibit credit extensions. These practices keep prices balanced and help prevent
aggressive deep discounting.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Appendix: Sources for Information
Issues relating to the history and purpose of alcohol regulation:
1. Aren't our alcohol regulations antiquated? Weren't they designed to prevent organized crime and other
problems of Prohibition?
"The Origins of the Washington State Liquor Control Board, 1934", By Rorabaugh, W. J., Pacific
Northwest Quarterly, Fall 2009.
Toward Liquor Control, Raymond Fosdick and Albert L. Scott, originally published in 1933,
republished by the Center for Alcohol Policy, 2011.
"Public Opinion on Alcohol Policies in the United States: Results from a National Survey",
Alexander C. Wagenaar, Eileen M. Harwood, Traci L. Toomey, Charles E. Denk and Kay M.
Zander, Journal of Public Health Policy.
2. Why do we need regulations to balance our alcohol market systems?
"Why can't we sell alcohol like tires and mayonnaise?" a PowerPoint presentation by Pamela S.
Erickson available at healthyalcoholmarket.com
"Big Beer, A Moral Market, and Innovation," By Barry C. Lynn, New America Foundation,
January 2, 2013 1 Harvard Business Review
3. Since alcohol is a legal product, why can't it be sold like orange juice or any other legal product?
"Alcohol, No Ordinary Commodity," Second Edition, Thomas Babor, et al, Oxford University
Press, 2010.
Center for Disease Control Fact Sheet, cdc.gov/alcohol/fact-sheets/alcohol-use.htm
"Traffic Safety Facts, 2013 Data, Alcohol Impaired Driving," National Highway Traffic Safety
Administration. http://www-nrd.nhtsa.dot.gov/Pubs/812102.pdf
4. What are some real-world examples of what happened when alcohol was deregulated?
"The Danger of Alcohol Deregulation: the United Kingdom Experience," and "The Dangers of
Alcohol Deregulation: The United Kingdom Experience, 2012 Update by Pamela S. Erickson, a
report available at healthyalcoholmarket.com.
"Last Call. Industry giants are threatening to swallow up America's carefully regulated alcohol
industry, and remake America in the image of booze -soaked Britain," by Tim Heffernan,
Washington Monthly, November/ December 2012.
"Health in alcohol policies: the European Union and its Nordic Member States," Christopher
Tigerstedt, et al.
"Finland's u -turn on alcohol tax," by Branwen Jeffrey, BBC News health correspondent.
"Major alcohol reforms pass into law, The New Zealand Herald, by Isaac Davison, December 11,
2012.
Life expectancy: who.int/gho/data/node. country. country- RUS
WHO Country profiles: who.int/substance abuse/publications/ lg obal alcohol report/profiles/en/index html#U
University of Oxford: ox.ac.uk/media/news stories/2009/090626.html
The Atlantic: How alcohol conquered Russia: theatlantic.com/international/archive/2013/09/how-
alcohol-conquered-russia/279965/
Finland: yle.fi/uutiset/ministry memo tighter controls higher taxes for_alcohol/6787407,
news.bbc.co.uk/2/lii/health/7846842.stm, yle.fi/uutiset/majority opposes pricier alcohol/6751023
www.eurocare.org/resources/country profiles/finland; yle.fi/uutiset/new chief backs calls for tighter alcohol
laws?7139049, stm.fi/en/pressreleases/pressrelease/-/view/1857950; yle.fi/uutiset/new laws limit travelers
alcohol important from ljuly/7330356.
NZ: justice. govt. nz/policy/sale- and- supply -of -alcohol; transport.govt.nz/assets/Uploads/Research
/Documents/alcohol- drugs- carshfacts-2013 .pdf; police. govt.nz/advice/drugs-and-alcohol/alcohol-
laws-and-penalties; nzherald.co.nz/nz/news/article.cfm?c id=1 &obi ected=11367224; The Lancet,
Volume 350, No. 9075, p383-388, 9 August 1997, "Huge variation in Russian mortality rates
1984-94: artefact, alcohol, or what?"
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Appendix: Sources for Information Continued
How our regulatory system works:
5. What does a good alcohol regulatory system look like?
"What are the most effective and cost-effective interventions in alcohol control?" World Health
Organization, February 2004, who.int (Nelson et al / Am J Prev Med 2013 3;45(l):19 - 28,
alpmonline. oEg
6. Why are some states in the liquor business? Can't a control state just convert to a license state and save
money?
"Alcohol Deregulation by Ballot Measure in Washington State
A Status Report on the Implementation of Measure 1183," by Pamela S. Erickson, Public Action
Management, 2014, www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
"The Effects of Privatization of Alcohol Control systems," The Alcohol Research Group, 2009, an
update of a previous version by the Pacific Institute for Research and Evaluation. Available at:
nabca.or-g
"Recommendations on Preventing Excessive Alcohol Consumption: Privatization of
Retail Alcohol Sales," Task Force on Community Prevention Services, available at:
thecommunity,guide. org
"The Illusion of Privatization Success: An Inventory of Tricks", Updated February, 2012, by
Roland Zullo, Research Scientist, Institute for Research on Labor, Employment and the Economy,
University of Michigan.
"The Fiscal and Social Effects of State Alcohol Control Systems", by Roland Zullo et al., Institute
for Research on Labor, Employment and the Economy, University of Michigan, May 2013.
7. Why are beer, wine and spirits regulated differently?
"The High Cost of Cheap Alcohol," Pamela S. Erickson, a report available at:
healthyalcoholmarket. com
Toward Liquor Control, Raymond Fosdick and Albert L. Scott, originally published in 1933,
republished by the Center for Alcohol Policy, 2011.
Map courtesy of National Alcohol Beverage Control Association.
8. What are the benefits of the three-tier system of alcohol control?
"The High Cost of Cheap Alcohol," Pamela S. Erickson, a report available at:
healthyalcoholmarket. com.
Toward Liquor Control, Raymond Fosdick and Albert L. Scott, originally published in 1933,
republished by the Center for Alcohol Policy, 2011.
"Last Call. Industry giants are threatening to swallow up America's carefully regulated alcohol
industry, and remake America in the image of booze -soaked Britain," by Tim Heffernan,
Washington Monthly, November/ December 2012.
Affidavit of Pamela S. Erickson, Anheuser-Busch, Inc. et al., v. Stephen B. Schnorf, et al. Case
No.: 10 -CV -01601, US District Court, Northern District of Illinois, Eastern District.
"Safe and Sound, How the three-tier system of U.S. alcohol regulations helps ensure safe products
and protects against revenue loss", Barry Finnemore, produced by Public Action Management,
available at healthyalcoholmarket.com.
9. Isn't alcohol regulation bad for business? Shouldn't we loosen alcohol regulations to help local
business?
"The High Price of Cheap Alcohol," Pamela S. Erickson, a report available at
healthyalcoholmarket. com
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
Appendix: Sources for Information Continued
Individual system elements:
10. Since the recession, all Americans expect good values, so what's the problem with lower prices for
alcohol?
"Effects of beverage alcohol price and tax levels on drinking: a meta-analysis of 1003 estimates
from 112 studies," Alexander C. Wagenaar, Matthew J. Salois & Kelli A. Komro. University of
Florida, College of Medicine, Department of Epidemiology and Health Policy Research,
Gainesville, FL, USA.
Bureau of Labor Statistics
11. Why shouldn't alcohol be more convenient for customers to buy?
"Recommendations on maintaining limits on days and hours of sale of alcoholic beverages to
prevent excessive alcohol consumption and related harms." Task Force on Community Preventive
Services. Am J Prev Med 2010; 39(6):605-6. Available at: thecommunityguide.org
"Health Behaviors of Adults: United States, 2005-2007," Centers for Disease Control and
Prevention.
"4 Ways American Grocery Shopping Is Changing Forever," Hayley Peterson, Business Insider,
Apr. 15, 2014, http://www.businessinsider.com/trends-that-are-changing-grocery-stores-2014-
4#ixzz3 OkHw 1 C 8 W
12. What is the problem with allowing more stores to sell alcohol?
"Recommendations for reducing excessive alcohol consumption and alcohol-related harms by
limiting alcohol outlet density." Task Force on Community Preventive Services. Am J Prev Med
2009; 37(6):570-1. Available at: thecommunityguide.org
"Glendale, Arizona Smart Policing Initiative, Reducing convenience Store Thefts," Smart Policing
Initiative, Spotlight, March 2012, Bureau of Justice Assistance, US Department of Justice.
13. Why are there special hours for alcohol sales? Why do some states prohibit alcohol sales on Sunday
or holidays?
"Recommendations on maintaining limits on days and hours of sale of alcoholic beverages to
prevent excessive alcohol consumption and related harms.Task Force on Community Preventive
Services." Am J Prev Med 2010; 39(6):605-6. Available at: thecommunityauide.org
Revenue and safety:
14. Can't we save taxpayers some money by eliminating the liquor cops and using local law enforcement
or state police instead?
Deregulation by Defunding, Why We Shouldn't Let the Players Make the Rules When it Comes to
Alcohol, By: Pat Gagliardi, President, Gagliardi Associates, Former Michigan Liquor Control
Commissioner, Former Floor Leader of the Michigan House of Representatives. To be published?
15. Why don't we have problems with fake alcohol or tax revenue loss?
"The `Fake Alcohol' Situation in the United States: The Impact of Culture, Market Economics,
and the Current RegulatoryS stems," by Robert M. Tobiassen, Former Chief Counsel for the
United States Alcohol and Tobacco Tax and Trade, Center for Alcohol Policy.
"An Analysis of the Structure and Administration of State and Local Taxes Imposed on the
Distribution and Sale of Beer," Prepared for the National Beer Wholesalers Association, by
Washington National Tax, KPMG LLP, Washington, DC, March 2009.
"Safe and Sound, The Three -Tier Alcohol Regulatory System: Ensuring Safe Products, Protecting
against Revenue Loss", by Barry Finnemore, produced by Public Action Management, Feb. 2013.
16. What are trade practice regulations and why do we need them for alcohol?
"Efficacy and the Strength of Evidence of U.S. Alcohol Control Policies", Toben F. Nelson et al.,
Am J Prev Med 2013; 45(1_):19-28.
"The Government turns the screws on alcohol fraudsters," Wholesale News, December 2013.
Available at: wholesalenews.co.uk/news.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com
About the Author
The author of this paper is a former alcohol regulator. From 1996 to 2003, she was the
executive director of the Oregon Liquor Control Commission. She left that position to work for Oregon
Partnership in the non-profit field of alcohol abuse prevention, specializing in the reduction of underage
drinking. As a prevention advocate, she gained an increased appreciation for the value of alcohol
regulation and its effectiveness as demonstrated by credible research.
In 2007, she began development of the "Campaign for a Healthy Alcohol Marketplace." She
became concerned that few people really understood alcohol regulatory systems in the United States and
how they work to reduce alcohol consumption and attendant problems. She realized that even as a
regulator she did not entirely understand many of the complex regulations that govern the alcohol
market. The concern was that important regulations could be lost merely out of ignorance. Her aim with
the "Campaign for a Healthy Alcohol Marketplace" is to educate those involved with alcohol issues about
the important role these regulations play.
This report is one of several reports available free of charge on the following
website: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com. Other reports include: "The Danger of Alcohol
Deregulation: The United Kingdom Experience" published in September, 2009 and an update published in
2012; "The High Cost of Cheap Alcohol," (2011), "Alcohol Deregulation by Ballot Measure in Washington
State, a status report on the implementation of Measure 1183". (2014) "Safe and Sound, how the 3 tier
alcohol regulatory system promotes safe products and high revenue collections." (2013) A monthly
newsletter provides readers with short, easy to read synopses of more current issues. In addition to these
publications, she has produced numerous PowerPoint presentations and articles. While materials are
copy written, they may be downloaded and copied as long as they are not altered without the author's
permission.
Photo Credits
Photos and illustrations in this publication were produced by Lise Gervais, a free-lance artist and
writer working in Portland, Oregon.
For more information: www.healthyalcoholmarket.com